Lesson 33ª


 

 

 

 

 

   

 

Purchasing Power Parity (PPP)

The "Purchasing Power Parity" theory claims that the exchange rate of two currencies should mean that one currency has the same purchasing power in any part of the world.

If you can buy a television for $1000 in the USA, with the same amount of money you should be able to buy one in Spain, Japan or Asia.

The international referee is the person that ensures that this law is fulfilled:

The international referee is backed up by numerous investors and speculators that observe the international markets looking for "bargains": differences in price between two markets that allows people to buy things for less money in one place and then sell for more in another, therefore making a profit without running any risks.

If the purchasing power parity is not fulfilled, this allows the referees to carry out their operations of buying-selling, and the same person makes the exchange rate move until it fulfills the parity law.

Let's look at an example:

Let's suppose that the exchange rate Yen/$ is 100 (with one dollar you can buy 100 yens) and that the same car in the USA costs 10.000 dólares and in Japan 900.000 yens.

The price of this car in the Japanese market (converting it into dollars) would be 9000 dollars, which would make the American car sellers import this car from Japan and then sell it in the USA, making a profit of 1000 dollars, simply because of the difference in price.

This will cause a great increase in yens because of the American import companies, which will make it appreciate. The balanced exchange rate will be reached when the price expressed in dollars is the same in both markets.

900.000 yens / Exchange rate = 10.000 $

Then the balanced exchange rate = 900.000 / 10.000 = 90 Yens/$

With this new exchange rate, the price of this car (expressed in dollars) will be the same in Japan as in the United States (10.000 dólares).

As the level of prices vary according to the country, the nominal exchange rate (the rate that we all know and which does not alter prices) will have to adjust to the differences in prices and ensure parity is achieved.

This adjustment in the nominal exchange rate will allow the real exchange rate to remain constant, maintaining purchasing power parity.

Let's continue with the previous example:

To start with lets take the balanced exchange rate as (90 yenes/$). After a year the prices in the USA go up by 5% and in Japan they go up by 10% (if we consider the prices in both countries with a base of 100 at the start of the year, after this year the index will be 105 in USA and 110 in Japan).

Bearing inflation in mind, the price of a car will now be 10.500 dollars in the American market and 990.00 yens in the Japanese market.

The new nominal interest rate to ensure Purchasing Power Parity is:

990.000 yens / Exchange rate = 10.500 $

Then, the new balanced interest rate will be = 990.000 / 10.500 = 94,28 Yens/$

The exchange rate of the yen compared with the dollar will have deflated to compensate for the increase in prices.

The variation of the nominal exchange rate responds to the following formula:

Tcr = Tc * (Pext / Pint)

In this equation:

"Tcr" = Real exchange rate

"Tc" = Nominal exchange rate

"Pext" = Level of prices abroad

"Pint " = Level of prices in the country

We are now going to apply this formula to the example that we are looking at:

Tc = 90 * 110 / 105 = 94,28

In real life, the theory behind Purchasing Power Parity has proved valid in general terms, but determined factors make it difficult for it to happen:

Services that are difficult to commercialize: a hair cut can be more expensive in Madrid than in Paris.

Other goods can be commercialized but their transport costs are very high: a brick can be more expensive in France than in Spain but the transport costs probably overcome the difference in prices.